REGIUS
PROFESSOR
OF MODERN HISTORY
EDITED BY
J.
EDITED BY
J.
Cambridge Medieval History - v5 - Contest of Empire and the Papacy
This file was downloaded from HathiTrust Digital Library.
Find more books at https://www. hathitrust. org.
Title: The Cambridge medieval history / planned by J. B. Bury . . . ;
edited by H. M. Gwatkin . . . J. P. Whitney
Publisher: New York : Macmillan, 1926-36
Copyright:
Public Domain in the United States, Google-digitized
http://www. hathitrust. org/access_use#pd-us-google
We have determined this work to be in the public domain in the United
States of America. It may not be in the public domain in other countries.
Copies are provided as a preservation service. Particularly outside of the
United States, persons receiving copies should make appropriate efforts to
determine the copyright status of the work in their country and use the
work accordingly. It is possible that current copyright holders, heirs or
the estate of the authors of individual portions of the work, such as
illustrations or photographs, assert copyrights over these portions.
Depending on the nature of subsequent use that is made, additional rights
may need to be obtained independently of anything we can address. The
digital images and OCR of this work were produced by Google, Inc.
(indicated by a watermark on each page in the PageTurner). Google requests
that the images and OCR not be re-hosted, redistributed or used
commercially. The images are provided for educational, scholarly,
non-commercial purposes.
Find this book online: https://hdl. handle. net/2027/mdp. 39015002257767
This file has been created from the computer-extracted text of scanned page
images. Computer-extracted text may have errors, such as misspellings,
unusual characters, odd spacing and line breaks.
Original from: University of Michigan
Digitized by: Google
Generated at University of Chicago on 2023-01-10 06:40 GMT
## p. (#1) ##################################################
B 1,284,344
## p. (#2) ##################################################
University of
Michigan
Libraries
tos SCIENTIA VIITAT
## p. i (#3) ################################################
## p. ii (#4) ###############################################
## p. iii (#5) ##############################################
D
THE
Icile
1923
CAMBRIDGE
MEDIEVAL HISTORY
top 3
PLANNED BY
J. B. BURY, M. A. , F. B. A.
REGIUS PROFESSOR OF MODERN HISTORY
EDITED BY
J. R. TANNER, Litt. D.
C. W. PREVITÉ-ORTON, M. A.
Z. N. BROOKE, M. A.
VOLUME V
CONTEST OF EMPIRE AND PAPACY
NEW YORK
THE MACMILLAN COMPANY
1926
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
IV
502
## p. iv (#6) ###############################################
PRINTED IN GREAT BRITAIN
## p. v (#7) ################################################
GRRY tu to al 2/87
hardoa
au
PREFACE.
N the Preface to Volume IV the Editors referred to the loss which
the enterprise had sustained by the death of Sir Edwin Pears before
he saw his chapter in type, and of M. Ferdinand Chalandon when he
had only seen the first proofs of his chapters, although in this case they
were able to obtain a second revision by Madame Chalandon of her
husband's proofs. They are also indebted to her for a similar revision
in the present volume. But another misfortune has befallen Volume V,
for Count Ugo Balzani died before he could revise his chapters, and this
duty has been discharged by the Editors themselves. They were obliged
to abbreviate them to a certain extent, but except in one instance, duly
indicated in a foot-note, they made no real change in the author's state-
ment of his conclusions.
They wish to express their gratitude to Mrs Stenton for under-
taking the chapter on Henry II of England at short notice, and for the
promptitude with which she completed the work; to Mr C. J. B. Gaskoin
of Jesus College for preparing the maps; and to Mr C. C. Scott, Sub-
Librarian of St John's College, for indispensable assistance in preparing
the bibliographies for the press. The index has been compiled by
Mr E. H. F. Mills of St John's College, the Librarian of the University
of Birmingham.
For the Corrigenda to Volume IV, the Editors are mainly indebted
to the kindness of Mr E. W. Brooks.
Since this Preface was in type, the Cambridge History School has
suffered a grievous loss by the death of Mr W. J. Corbett of King's
College, whose original researches in English history have already lent
distinction to Volumes II and III, and whose last work appears in the
present volume. Even if his researches on Domesday should never now
be published, his main conclusions will be found in the Cambridge
Medieval History.
J. R. T.
C. W. P. -O.
Z. N. B.
January, 1926.
## p. vi (#8) ###############################################
1
## p. vii (#9) ##############################################
INTRODUCTION.
The century and a half, roughly from 1050 to 1200, with which this
volume is concerned, follows on a period when the disorganisation and
anarchy of the ninth century had barely been made good. Order had
been to some extent restored; the desire for order and for peace was at
any rate widespread. The opportunity for fruitful development, both in
the sphere of ecclesiastical and of secular government, and also in those
pursuits which especially needed peace for their prosecution, such as
culture and commerce, had now arrived. We have to deal, then, with a
period, on the one hand, of new movements and new ideas—the appearance
of new monastic orders, a renaissance of thought and learning, the rise of
towns and the expansion of commerce; on the other, of consolidation and
centralisation-the organisation of the monarchical government of the
Church, the development of monarchical institutions in the various
countries of Europe, and, to give direction and solidity to the whole, the
revived study of Civil and Canon Law. Finally, and most novel of all,
we see Europe at once divided by the great conflict of Empire and Papacy
and united by the Crusades in the holy war against the infidel. The
former as well as the latter implies a conception of the unity of Western
Christendom, a unity which found expression in the universal Church,
For the Church alone was universal, European, international; and, as its
institutions begin to take more definite form, the more deeply is this
character impressed upon them.
The volume opens with a chapter on the Reform of the Church,
which was not merely a prelude to, but also a principal cause of, the
striking events that followed; for in the pursuit of the work of reform
the Papacy both developed its own organisation and was brought into
conflict with the secular power. In the first half of the eleventh century,
it had been entirely dominated by the secular interests of the local nobles.
It had been rescued by the Emperor Henry III, and Pope Leo IX had
immediately taken his natural place as leader of the reform movement.
When he undertook personally, in France, Germany, and Italy, the
promulgation and enforcement of the principles of reform, he made the
universality of papal power a reality; the bishops might mutter, but the
people adored. The Papacy was content to take a subordinate place
while Henry III was alive; Henry IV's minority worked a complete
## p. viii (#10) ############################################
viii
Introduction
change. The first great step was the Papal Election Decree of Nicholas
II, and, though the attempt of the Roman nobles to recover their influence
was perhaps the immediate cause, the Papacy took the opportunity to
shake off imperial control as well. An opening for interference still
remained in the case of a disputed election, as was clearly shewn in the
contest of Innocent II and Anastasius II, and especially in that of
Alexander III and Victor IV. This gap was closed by the Third Lateran
Council in 1179, which decreed that whoever obtained the votes of two-
thirds of the cardinals should be declared Pope.
The Papal Election Decree had a further result. By giving to the
cardinals the decision at an election, and reducing other interests to a
merely nominal right of assent, it raised the College of Cardinals to a
position of the highest importance. There were normally at this time
7 (later 6) cardinal-bishops, 28 cardinal-priests, and 18 cardinal-deacons,
and, unless they were employed on papal business, their functions were
confined to Rome. Leo IX had surrounded himself with cardinals who
were reformers like himself; they composed the chief element in the Pope's
Council, or, as it came to be called, the Curia. But he could not find
them in Rome, and had to recruit them from the chief reforming centres,
especially north of the Alps. As they were, and continued to be, drawn from
different countries, so in them was displayed the international character
of the Roman Church; and from their number, in almost every case, was
the Pope elected. A further development came when Alexander III
instituted the practice of including bishops from different parts of
Europe among the cardinals; for the regular duties and residence of such
cardinals were no longer in Rome itself.
The freedom of episcopal elections in general was in the forefront of
the reform programme. The papal policy was to restore canonical
election “by clergy and people," a vague phrase which received its
definition at Rome in the Election Decree. During the twelfth century
a similar definition was arrived at for other sees. The cathedral chapter,
helped by its corporate unity, and especially by the fact that it constituted
the permanent portion of the bishop's concilium and that its consent was
necessary in any disposition of the property of the see, established itself
as the electoral body. To the clergy of the diocese and the lay vassals of
the see was left, as at Rome, only the right of assent and acclamation.
The chapter thus became the local counterpart of the College of Cardinals.
The Papacy was principally concerned with the freedom of elections, and
did not yet claim the right of appointment for itself, except in cases of
dispute. The Third Lateran Council, which gave the decision at a papal
election to a majority vote, expressly decreed that elsewhere the old rule
## p. ix (#11) ##############################################
Introduction
ix
of the “maior et sanior pars” was to hold good; for, with the exception
of Rome, there was a higher authority which could decide in cases of
dispute.
Leo IX had initiated the campaign of reform at Councils in France and
Germany. The Councils over which the Popes presided passed decrees
which were to be universally binding. Usually they were held in Rome,
and regularly in Lent by Gregory VII. In them, besides the Curia, any
leading ecclesiastic who happened to be at the papal court, whether on a
visit or in obedience to a personal summons, took part, just as the nobles
did in a king's Council. A further development occurred in the twelfth
century. Hitherto all the Councils recognised by the Western Church as
Ecumenical had taken place in the East. The schism of 1054 had cut off
the Greek Church from communion with Rome, and in the twelfth
century three Councils were held, each of them at Rome in the Lateran
basilica, which, owing to the importance of their business and the general
rather than particular summonses which were issued, were included later
among the Ecumenical Councils. The First Lateran Council in 1123
ratified the Concordat of Worms, the Second in 1139 solemnised the end
of a schism, and the Third in 1179 the end of another and a greater one.
The next step was the local enforcement of the papal decrees. The
Church had its local officials—archbishops, bishops etc. —and they were
expected both to promulgate the decrees at local synods and to enforce
their execution. It soon became clear that the bishops regarded them-
selves as anything but the docile officials of the central government, and
the Papacy had to establish its authority and to work out a coordinated
system of government by which its policy could be carried into effect.
First of all, for the Pope could no longer do everything in person
like
Leo IX, legates were sent to act in his name, travelling about, like the
Carolingian missi, with overriding authority, to investigate the local
churches and put into force the papal decrees. The appointment of legates
for this general work tends more and more to take a permanent form, and
soon the post of permanent legate—a position of high honour and at the
same time of personal responsibility to the Pope-becomes the prerogative
of the leading ecclesiastics in each country. But the Pope still continued
to send legates from Rome, both as ambassadors to temporal sovereigns
and as functionaries with special commissions; these legates a latere as
direct papal agents again had overriding powers. It was not sufficient,
however, for the Pope to control the local officials through his repre-
sentatives. He insisted on their personal contact with himself. Visits
ad limina were first of all encouraged and then directly ordered, and
archbishops were expected to receive the pallium from the Pope in person. .
## p. x (#12) ###############################################
X
Introduction
It is impossible to say how far at any time this development of papal
authority was deliberate, and how far it arose out of the practical
exigencies of the moment. It became conscious at any rate with Gregory
VII, though even with him the moving cause at first was to enforce the
principles of reform. Opposition, whether from the local officials or from
the lay power, led to a definition of the bases on which this authority
rested and the sphere within which it could be exercised. The decretals,
especially the Forged Decretals, provided a solid foundation, and to
build upon this came opportunely the revived study of the Canon Law.
It is not a question of a finished legal system, but of a continuous process
of construction, in which the legal training of Popes like Urban II and
Alexander III was of great value. Collections of decretals and opinions,
of which Gratian's was the most complete, were continually being added
to by the decrees of Roman Councils and the decisions of Popes given in
their letters. This led to uniformity in ritual also, to the victory of the
Roman use over local customs; for here again it was the Roman that
was to be universal.
In the papal government, even on its ecclesiastical side, there is a
general resemblance to the secular governments of the day. Like a lay
monarch, the Pope was concerned with the organisation of central and
local government, with the formation of a legal system, and with the
recognition of his overriding jurisdiction. When we come to the secular
side of papal government, the resemblance is still more close. Both as
landlord and overlord the Pope acted as any secular ruler, though payments
in money and kind are the usual services rendered to him, rather than
military service; for this he was really dependent on external assistance.
The problem of finance faced him, as it faced every secular ruler. The
work of government, both ecclesiastical and secular, involved the expenses
of government, and, though in ordinary times the revenue from the Papal
States might be sufficient, a period of conflict, by increasing expenditure
or by preventing the Pope from obtaining his ordinary revenues, would
create serious financial difficulties. This was especially the case with
Urban II, and still more with Alexander III, in the crisis of the conflict
with the Empire; and, in the interval of peace, the Pope was seriously
embarrassed by the sustained effort of the Roman people to obtain self-
government.
We have a detailed account of various sources of papal revenue at the
end of our period in the Liber Censuum drawn up under the direction of
the camerarius Cencius, afterwards Pope Honorius III, in the year 1192.
Besides the revenue from the papal domain proper, a census
received: (1) from monasteries who had placed themselves under the papal
was
## p. xi (#13) ##############################################
Introduction
xi
"protection," and who in the course of the twelfth century gained
exemption from the spiritual as well as the temporal control of their
diocesans ; (2) from some lay rulers and nobles, who put themselves under
papal “protection " or, like the kings of Aragon and the Norman rulers
of South Italy and Sicily, recognised papal overlordship; (3) in the form
of Peter's Pence, from England since Anglo-Saxon times, and, in the
twelfth century, from Norway, Sweden, and some other countries as well.
But the census provided only a relatively small revenue, and this was
difficult to collect; there were frequent complaints of arrears of payment,
especially with regard to Peter's Pence. On the other hand, the papal ex-
penditure was often heavy. Alexander III had frequently to have recourse
to borrowing; and his complaints about some of his creditors seem to have
an echo in the decree against usury at the Third Lateran Council. In its
difficulties the Papacy had to depend upon the voluntary offerings of the
faithful, especially from France, on subsidies from the Normans, or on
the support of a wealthy Roman family; thus the Pierleoni constantly
supplied the Popes with money, until one member of the family,
Anacletus II, was defeated in his attempt to ascend the papal throne.
We are still in the early days of papal financial history. Not yet were
the visitation offerings from bishops made compulsory, and the servitia
taxes and annates had not yet been introduced. Nor did the Popes claim
the right to tax the clergy, though perhaps the first step to this was taken
in the second half of the twelfth century, when prohibitions were issued
against the taxation of the clergy by lay rulers without papal consent.
At any rate the desire to finance the Crusades soon led them to assert the
right.
As the Reform Movement had led directly to the creation of a
centralised government of the Church, so too it led, almost inevitably, to
the contest for supremacy between the Papacy and its counterpart on the
secular side, the Empire. Those ecclesiastics whom the Pope expected to
be his obedient officials in the local government of the Church were
already the obedient officials of the Empire both in its central and its
local government. The Pope was on strong ground in insisting that the
spiritual duties of the bishop were his primary consideration. But the
Emperor was on strong ground too. The ecclesiastical nobles were an
essential part of the economic framework and the political machinery of
the Empire, and to justify his authority over them the Emperor could
point to an almost unbroken tradition. The relative importance of
spiritual and temporal considerations in the medieval mind gave an
initial advantage to the Pope, and in the end the victory. On the other
## p. xii (#14) #############################################
xii
Introduction
hand, the Emperor could appeal not only to the iron law of necessity, but
to the medieval reverence for custom and precedent. Henry IV, moreover,
could not forget that the Papacy had itself been subject to his father, and
it was his object to recover what he considered to be his lawful authority.
With this aim he deliberately provoked the contest. The details of the
struggle are described in several chapters in this volume, and need only
be briefly alluded to here. Henry's challenge was taken up by his greater
opponent, Pope Gregory VII, who in his turn claimed the supreme power
for the Papacy; there could be no real peace until the question of
supremacy was settled. Though on this issue the first contest was
indecisive, the Papacy registered a striking advance. The Concordat of
Worms marked a definite limitation of imperial authority over the
ecclesiastical nobility, and it was followed by the reigns of Lothar III and
Conrad III, when the German ruler was too complaisant or too weak to
press his claims. The Pope was emboldened to take the offensive, and
Hadrian IV threw down the challenge that was taken up by Frederick
Barbarossa. The positions were reversed, but again the challenger found
himself faced by a greater opponent, who again defended himself by
asserting his own supremacy. Once more the result was indecisive.
The Pope had a single cause to maintain, the Emperor a dual one.
i Henry IV was defeated by revolt in Germany, Frederick Barbarossa by
revolt in Italy, and both alike had been forced to recognise the
impossibility of maintaining a subservient anti-Pope. But the greatness
of Frederick was never so conspicuous as in his recovery after defeat, and
his son Henry VI seemed to be on the point of making the Empire once
more supreme when death intervened to ruin the imperial cause. Herein
was revealed the second great asset of the Papacy. Built on the rock of
spiritual power, the weakness or death of its head was of little permanent
moment. The Empire, however, depended on the personality of each of
its rulers, and the transference of authority on the deaths of Henry III
and Henry VI was on each occasion disastrous. During the minority of
Henry IV, the Papacy had built up its power; in the minority of
Frederick II, Innocent III was Pope.
In this struggle of Empire and Papacy no insignificant part was played
by the Norman rulers of South Italy and Sicily, whose history falls
exactly within the compass of this volume. Frequently did they come to
the help of the Papacy in its extremity, and skilfully did they make use
of papal exigencies to improve their own position. Only once did the
Pope whom they supported fail to maintain himself; and the victory of
Innocent II over Anastasius II, chosen by a majority of the cardinals and
backed by Norman arms, was in many respects unique. Then, and then
!
REGIUS PROFESSOR OF MODERN HISTORY
EDITED BY
J. R. TANNER, Litt. D.
C. W. PREVITÉ-ORTON, M. A.
Z. N. BROOKE, M. A.
VOLUME V
CONTEST OF EMPIRE AND PAPACY
NEW YORK
THE MACMILLAN COMPANY
1926
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
IV
502
## p. iv (#6) ###############################################
PRINTED IN GREAT BRITAIN
## p. v (#7) ################################################
GRRY tu to al 2/87
hardoa
au
PREFACE.
N the Preface to Volume IV the Editors referred to the loss which
the enterprise had sustained by the death of Sir Edwin Pears before
he saw his chapter in type, and of M. Ferdinand Chalandon when he
had only seen the first proofs of his chapters, although in this case they
were able to obtain a second revision by Madame Chalandon of her
husband's proofs. They are also indebted to her for a similar revision
in the present volume. But another misfortune has befallen Volume V,
for Count Ugo Balzani died before he could revise his chapters, and this
duty has been discharged by the Editors themselves. They were obliged
to abbreviate them to a certain extent, but except in one instance, duly
indicated in a foot-note, they made no real change in the author's state-
ment of his conclusions.
They wish to express their gratitude to Mrs Stenton for under-
taking the chapter on Henry II of England at short notice, and for the
promptitude with which she completed the work; to Mr C. J. B. Gaskoin
of Jesus College for preparing the maps; and to Mr C. C. Scott, Sub-
Librarian of St John's College, for indispensable assistance in preparing
the bibliographies for the press. The index has been compiled by
Mr E. H. F. Mills of St John's College, the Librarian of the University
of Birmingham.
For the Corrigenda to Volume IV, the Editors are mainly indebted
to the kindness of Mr E. W. Brooks.
Since this Preface was in type, the Cambridge History School has
suffered a grievous loss by the death of Mr W. J. Corbett of King's
College, whose original researches in English history have already lent
distinction to Volumes II and III, and whose last work appears in the
present volume. Even if his researches on Domesday should never now
be published, his main conclusions will be found in the Cambridge
Medieval History.
J. R. T.
C. W. P. -O.
Z. N. B.
January, 1926.
## p. vi (#8) ###############################################
1
## p. vii (#9) ##############################################
INTRODUCTION.
The century and a half, roughly from 1050 to 1200, with which this
volume is concerned, follows on a period when the disorganisation and
anarchy of the ninth century had barely been made good. Order had
been to some extent restored; the desire for order and for peace was at
any rate widespread. The opportunity for fruitful development, both in
the sphere of ecclesiastical and of secular government, and also in those
pursuits which especially needed peace for their prosecution, such as
culture and commerce, had now arrived. We have to deal, then, with a
period, on the one hand, of new movements and new ideas—the appearance
of new monastic orders, a renaissance of thought and learning, the rise of
towns and the expansion of commerce; on the other, of consolidation and
centralisation-the organisation of the monarchical government of the
Church, the development of monarchical institutions in the various
countries of Europe, and, to give direction and solidity to the whole, the
revived study of Civil and Canon Law. Finally, and most novel of all,
we see Europe at once divided by the great conflict of Empire and Papacy
and united by the Crusades in the holy war against the infidel. The
former as well as the latter implies a conception of the unity of Western
Christendom, a unity which found expression in the universal Church,
For the Church alone was universal, European, international; and, as its
institutions begin to take more definite form, the more deeply is this
character impressed upon them.
The volume opens with a chapter on the Reform of the Church,
which was not merely a prelude to, but also a principal cause of, the
striking events that followed; for in the pursuit of the work of reform
the Papacy both developed its own organisation and was brought into
conflict with the secular power. In the first half of the eleventh century,
it had been entirely dominated by the secular interests of the local nobles.
It had been rescued by the Emperor Henry III, and Pope Leo IX had
immediately taken his natural place as leader of the reform movement.
When he undertook personally, in France, Germany, and Italy, the
promulgation and enforcement of the principles of reform, he made the
universality of papal power a reality; the bishops might mutter, but the
people adored. The Papacy was content to take a subordinate place
while Henry III was alive; Henry IV's minority worked a complete
## p. viii (#10) ############################################
viii
Introduction
change. The first great step was the Papal Election Decree of Nicholas
II, and, though the attempt of the Roman nobles to recover their influence
was perhaps the immediate cause, the Papacy took the opportunity to
shake off imperial control as well. An opening for interference still
remained in the case of a disputed election, as was clearly shewn in the
contest of Innocent II and Anastasius II, and especially in that of
Alexander III and Victor IV. This gap was closed by the Third Lateran
Council in 1179, which decreed that whoever obtained the votes of two-
thirds of the cardinals should be declared Pope.
The Papal Election Decree had a further result. By giving to the
cardinals the decision at an election, and reducing other interests to a
merely nominal right of assent, it raised the College of Cardinals to a
position of the highest importance. There were normally at this time
7 (later 6) cardinal-bishops, 28 cardinal-priests, and 18 cardinal-deacons,
and, unless they were employed on papal business, their functions were
confined to Rome. Leo IX had surrounded himself with cardinals who
were reformers like himself; they composed the chief element in the Pope's
Council, or, as it came to be called, the Curia. But he could not find
them in Rome, and had to recruit them from the chief reforming centres,
especially north of the Alps. As they were, and continued to be, drawn from
different countries, so in them was displayed the international character
of the Roman Church; and from their number, in almost every case, was
the Pope elected. A further development came when Alexander III
instituted the practice of including bishops from different parts of
Europe among the cardinals; for the regular duties and residence of such
cardinals were no longer in Rome itself.
The freedom of episcopal elections in general was in the forefront of
the reform programme. The papal policy was to restore canonical
election “by clergy and people," a vague phrase which received its
definition at Rome in the Election Decree. During the twelfth century
a similar definition was arrived at for other sees. The cathedral chapter,
helped by its corporate unity, and especially by the fact that it constituted
the permanent portion of the bishop's concilium and that its consent was
necessary in any disposition of the property of the see, established itself
as the electoral body. To the clergy of the diocese and the lay vassals of
the see was left, as at Rome, only the right of assent and acclamation.
The chapter thus became the local counterpart of the College of Cardinals.
The Papacy was principally concerned with the freedom of elections, and
did not yet claim the right of appointment for itself, except in cases of
dispute. The Third Lateran Council, which gave the decision at a papal
election to a majority vote, expressly decreed that elsewhere the old rule
## p. ix (#11) ##############################################
Introduction
ix
of the “maior et sanior pars” was to hold good; for, with the exception
of Rome, there was a higher authority which could decide in cases of
dispute.
Leo IX had initiated the campaign of reform at Councils in France and
Germany. The Councils over which the Popes presided passed decrees
which were to be universally binding. Usually they were held in Rome,
and regularly in Lent by Gregory VII. In them, besides the Curia, any
leading ecclesiastic who happened to be at the papal court, whether on a
visit or in obedience to a personal summons, took part, just as the nobles
did in a king's Council. A further development occurred in the twelfth
century. Hitherto all the Councils recognised by the Western Church as
Ecumenical had taken place in the East. The schism of 1054 had cut off
the Greek Church from communion with Rome, and in the twelfth
century three Councils were held, each of them at Rome in the Lateran
basilica, which, owing to the importance of their business and the general
rather than particular summonses which were issued, were included later
among the Ecumenical Councils. The First Lateran Council in 1123
ratified the Concordat of Worms, the Second in 1139 solemnised the end
of a schism, and the Third in 1179 the end of another and a greater one.
The next step was the local enforcement of the papal decrees. The
Church had its local officials—archbishops, bishops etc. —and they were
expected both to promulgate the decrees at local synods and to enforce
their execution. It soon became clear that the bishops regarded them-
selves as anything but the docile officials of the central government, and
the Papacy had to establish its authority and to work out a coordinated
system of government by which its policy could be carried into effect.
First of all, for the Pope could no longer do everything in person
like
Leo IX, legates were sent to act in his name, travelling about, like the
Carolingian missi, with overriding authority, to investigate the local
churches and put into force the papal decrees. The appointment of legates
for this general work tends more and more to take a permanent form, and
soon the post of permanent legate—a position of high honour and at the
same time of personal responsibility to the Pope-becomes the prerogative
of the leading ecclesiastics in each country. But the Pope still continued
to send legates from Rome, both as ambassadors to temporal sovereigns
and as functionaries with special commissions; these legates a latere as
direct papal agents again had overriding powers. It was not sufficient,
however, for the Pope to control the local officials through his repre-
sentatives. He insisted on their personal contact with himself. Visits
ad limina were first of all encouraged and then directly ordered, and
archbishops were expected to receive the pallium from the Pope in person. .
## p. x (#12) ###############################################
X
Introduction
It is impossible to say how far at any time this development of papal
authority was deliberate, and how far it arose out of the practical
exigencies of the moment. It became conscious at any rate with Gregory
VII, though even with him the moving cause at first was to enforce the
principles of reform. Opposition, whether from the local officials or from
the lay power, led to a definition of the bases on which this authority
rested and the sphere within which it could be exercised. The decretals,
especially the Forged Decretals, provided a solid foundation, and to
build upon this came opportunely the revived study of the Canon Law.
It is not a question of a finished legal system, but of a continuous process
of construction, in which the legal training of Popes like Urban II and
Alexander III was of great value. Collections of decretals and opinions,
of which Gratian's was the most complete, were continually being added
to by the decrees of Roman Councils and the decisions of Popes given in
their letters. This led to uniformity in ritual also, to the victory of the
Roman use over local customs; for here again it was the Roman that
was to be universal.
In the papal government, even on its ecclesiastical side, there is a
general resemblance to the secular governments of the day. Like a lay
monarch, the Pope was concerned with the organisation of central and
local government, with the formation of a legal system, and with the
recognition of his overriding jurisdiction. When we come to the secular
side of papal government, the resemblance is still more close. Both as
landlord and overlord the Pope acted as any secular ruler, though payments
in money and kind are the usual services rendered to him, rather than
military service; for this he was really dependent on external assistance.
The problem of finance faced him, as it faced every secular ruler. The
work of government, both ecclesiastical and secular, involved the expenses
of government, and, though in ordinary times the revenue from the Papal
States might be sufficient, a period of conflict, by increasing expenditure
or by preventing the Pope from obtaining his ordinary revenues, would
create serious financial difficulties. This was especially the case with
Urban II, and still more with Alexander III, in the crisis of the conflict
with the Empire; and, in the interval of peace, the Pope was seriously
embarrassed by the sustained effort of the Roman people to obtain self-
government.
We have a detailed account of various sources of papal revenue at the
end of our period in the Liber Censuum drawn up under the direction of
the camerarius Cencius, afterwards Pope Honorius III, in the year 1192.
Besides the revenue from the papal domain proper, a census
received: (1) from monasteries who had placed themselves under the papal
was
## p. xi (#13) ##############################################
Introduction
xi
"protection," and who in the course of the twelfth century gained
exemption from the spiritual as well as the temporal control of their
diocesans ; (2) from some lay rulers and nobles, who put themselves under
papal “protection " or, like the kings of Aragon and the Norman rulers
of South Italy and Sicily, recognised papal overlordship; (3) in the form
of Peter's Pence, from England since Anglo-Saxon times, and, in the
twelfth century, from Norway, Sweden, and some other countries as well.
But the census provided only a relatively small revenue, and this was
difficult to collect; there were frequent complaints of arrears of payment,
especially with regard to Peter's Pence. On the other hand, the papal ex-
penditure was often heavy. Alexander III had frequently to have recourse
to borrowing; and his complaints about some of his creditors seem to have
an echo in the decree against usury at the Third Lateran Council. In its
difficulties the Papacy had to depend upon the voluntary offerings of the
faithful, especially from France, on subsidies from the Normans, or on
the support of a wealthy Roman family; thus the Pierleoni constantly
supplied the Popes with money, until one member of the family,
Anacletus II, was defeated in his attempt to ascend the papal throne.
We are still in the early days of papal financial history. Not yet were
the visitation offerings from bishops made compulsory, and the servitia
taxes and annates had not yet been introduced. Nor did the Popes claim
the right to tax the clergy, though perhaps the first step to this was taken
in the second half of the twelfth century, when prohibitions were issued
against the taxation of the clergy by lay rulers without papal consent.
At any rate the desire to finance the Crusades soon led them to assert the
right.
As the Reform Movement had led directly to the creation of a
centralised government of the Church, so too it led, almost inevitably, to
the contest for supremacy between the Papacy and its counterpart on the
secular side, the Empire. Those ecclesiastics whom the Pope expected to
be his obedient officials in the local government of the Church were
already the obedient officials of the Empire both in its central and its
local government. The Pope was on strong ground in insisting that the
spiritual duties of the bishop were his primary consideration. But the
Emperor was on strong ground too. The ecclesiastical nobles were an
essential part of the economic framework and the political machinery of
the Empire, and to justify his authority over them the Emperor could
point to an almost unbroken tradition. The relative importance of
spiritual and temporal considerations in the medieval mind gave an
initial advantage to the Pope, and in the end the victory. On the other
## p. xii (#14) #############################################
xii
Introduction
hand, the Emperor could appeal not only to the iron law of necessity, but
to the medieval reverence for custom and precedent. Henry IV, moreover,
could not forget that the Papacy had itself been subject to his father, and
it was his object to recover what he considered to be his lawful authority.
With this aim he deliberately provoked the contest. The details of the
struggle are described in several chapters in this volume, and need only
be briefly alluded to here. Henry's challenge was taken up by his greater
opponent, Pope Gregory VII, who in his turn claimed the supreme power
for the Papacy; there could be no real peace until the question of
supremacy was settled. Though on this issue the first contest was
indecisive, the Papacy registered a striking advance. The Concordat of
Worms marked a definite limitation of imperial authority over the
ecclesiastical nobility, and it was followed by the reigns of Lothar III and
Conrad III, when the German ruler was too complaisant or too weak to
press his claims. The Pope was emboldened to take the offensive, and
Hadrian IV threw down the challenge that was taken up by Frederick
Barbarossa. The positions were reversed, but again the challenger found
himself faced by a greater opponent, who again defended himself by
asserting his own supremacy. Once more the result was indecisive.
The Pope had a single cause to maintain, the Emperor a dual one.
i Henry IV was defeated by revolt in Germany, Frederick Barbarossa by
revolt in Italy, and both alike had been forced to recognise the
impossibility of maintaining a subservient anti-Pope. But the greatness
of Frederick was never so conspicuous as in his recovery after defeat, and
his son Henry VI seemed to be on the point of making the Empire once
more supreme when death intervened to ruin the imperial cause. Herein
was revealed the second great asset of the Papacy. Built on the rock of
spiritual power, the weakness or death of its head was of little permanent
moment. The Empire, however, depended on the personality of each of
its rulers, and the transference of authority on the deaths of Henry III
and Henry VI was on each occasion disastrous. During the minority of
Henry IV, the Papacy had built up its power; in the minority of
Frederick II, Innocent III was Pope.
In this struggle of Empire and Papacy no insignificant part was played
by the Norman rulers of South Italy and Sicily, whose history falls
exactly within the compass of this volume. Frequently did they come to
the help of the Papacy in its extremity, and skilfully did they make use
of papal exigencies to improve their own position. Only once did the
Pope whom they supported fail to maintain himself; and the victory of
Innocent II over Anastasius II, chosen by a majority of the cardinals and
backed by Norman arms, was in many respects unique. Then, and then
!
## p. xiii (#15) ############################################
Introduction
xiii
only, did Pope and Emperor combine against the Normans, but there was
no stability in an alliance so unusual. In the Sicilian kingdom were
displayed the peculiar characteristics of the Norman race—its military
prowess and ferocity, its genius for administration, its adaptability and
eclecticism. They brought from Normandy the feudal customs they had
there acquired, but they maintained and converted to their use the
officials and institutions, the arts and sciences, of the races they conquered-
Italian, Greek, and Arab—each of which was tolerated in the use of its
own language, religion, and customs. The court of Roger II at Palermo
presented an appearance unlike anything else in the West; and the
essential product of this extraordinary environment was “the wonder of
the world,” Frederick II. The Normans pieced together a most remarkable
mosaic, but they never made a nation of their subjects; the elements were
too discordant, and they themselves too few. They remained a ruling
caste, and then, as the royal house, once so prolific, gradually became
sterile, Frederick Barbarossa seized the opportunity to marry his son
Henry VI to the heiress Constance and to unite the crowns of Germany
and Sicily. But, though the Norman rulers had disappeared, their deeds
survived; for their own purposes they had recognised papal overlordship
and received from the Pope their titles as dukes and kings. By so doing
they added materially to the temporal authority of the Papacy, and
created the situation which made so bitter the conflict of Empire and
Papacy in the thirteenth century.
As the Normans exercised an important influence on the great
struggle which divided the unity of Europe, so did they also have a de-
cisive effect upon the other great struggle, in which Europe was united
against the infidel. The story of the Crusades is described in this volume
from the Western point of view, and it has already been told from the
Eastern standpoint in Volume IV. Its importance in world-history, and
also in the more limited field of European history, need not be stressed
here; but it is worth while to characterise the different interests involved,
and to regard the Crusading movement in its proper setting, as an episode
in the general history of the relations of East and West. It was not
merely a Holy War between Christian and Muslim. The Seljūqs, already
in decline and hampered by internal divisions, were concerned with the
effort to maintain what they had won. The Eastern Empire was con-
cerned firstly with the defence of its existence, secondly with the recovery
of Asia Minor. The Latins, to whom they appealed for help, were inte-
rested rather in Syria and Palestine, to which they were equally attracted
by religious enthusiasm and by the prospects of territory or trade. Europe
also had its own injuries to avenge. It too had suffered from Saracen
C. MED. H. VOL. V.
b
## p. xiv (#16) #############################################
xiv
Introduction
invaders, against whom it was now beginning to react—in the advance of
the Christian kingdoms in Spain, in the Norman conquest of Sicily, in
the capture of Mahdiyah by Genoa and Pisa in 1087. The Crusades were,
in one aspect, an extension Eastwards of this reaction, a change
from the defensive to the offensive. Against a common foe Eastern and
Western Christians had a common cause, but the concord went no further.
In the first place, seventeen years before the fatal battle of Manzikert,
which had caused the Eastern Empire to turn to the West for aid, the
great Schism between the Eastern and Western Churches had already
occurred. One of the results hoped for from the First Crusade was the
healing of that schism, and to the Western mind the obstinate perversity
of the Greek Church made it as dangerous an enemy of the faith as
Mohammedanism itself. And, secondly, the Normans in South Italy had
conquered Greeks as well as Saracens, and their first advance eastwards
was against Greeks not against Saracens. Robert Guiscard by his attack
on the Eastern Empire in 1081 began the policy, which was continued
by his successors and was adopted by the Emperor Henry VI as part of
his Norman inheritance. In other quarters, too, the experiences of the
first two Crusades created a body of opinion in favour of the conquest of
the Eastern Empire as a necessary part of the whole movement; this
opinion gathered strength when the Eastern Emperor came to terms with
Saladin to oppose the Western advance which was now a menace to both.
Finally, Venice was alienated by the ambition of Manuel Comnenus and
the folly of Andronicus, and from being the chief obstacle to the Norman
policy became its chief supporter. It was now the aim of the Crusaders
to conquer the whole of the Near East, Christian and Muslim alike, and
their first objective was Constantinople.
In the internal history of Europe this volume deals, outside Italy,
with the three leading countries of Germany, France, and England; the
history of the outlying and more backward countries—Spain, Scandinavia,
Poland, Bohemia, Hungary-is reserved for the next volume. In these
three countries there was much that was similar, for the underlying ideas
inherent in feudal society were common to them all. But similar concep-
tions produced widely differing results. On the one hand, feudal society
with its deep reverence for custom and tradition was much affected by
local conditions and lapse of time. On the other hand, it was peculiarly
sensitive to the workings of human nature, to the ambition of individuals
who stressed the privileges and minimised the obligations arising from the
idea of contract on which the feudal system was essentially based; it was
poised on a delicate balance which the accident of death might immedi-
## p. xv (#17) ##############################################
1
Introduction
XV
ately upset. In the secular governments, as in the ecclesiastical government
of the Church, the trend is in favour of monarchy, and the rulers make,
with varying success, a continual effort towards centralisation; but they
were all at an initial disadvantage compared with the Pope. The success
of the electoral principle might be fatal to monarchical authority; and
the hereditary principle had its dangers too, in the event of a minority
or the failure of a direct heir. The hereditary principle could not be
applied to the Papacy, for which the electoral system worked as a means
of continual development; for the cardinals, having no opportunity of
obtaining an independent position apart from the Pope, had everything
to gain as individuals and nothing to lose by electing the ablest of their
number as Pope.
Monarchy was in the most favourable position in England, and here
it was therefore the most successful. William I started with the initial
advantage that the whole land was his by conquest, and to be dealt with as
he chose. The Normans, here as in Sicily, displayed their genius in adminis-
tration, their adaptability and eclecticism. The political feudalism they
brought from Normandy placed the king in England in the strong posi-
tion that, as duke, he had held in Normandy; and he adopted what he
found suitable to his purpose already existing—the manorial system, the
shire and hundred courts, Danegeld.
Find more books at https://www. hathitrust. org.
Title: The Cambridge medieval history / planned by J. B. Bury . . . ;
edited by H. M. Gwatkin . . . J. P. Whitney
Publisher: New York : Macmillan, 1926-36
Copyright:
Public Domain in the United States, Google-digitized
http://www. hathitrust. org/access_use#pd-us-google
We have determined this work to be in the public domain in the United
States of America. It may not be in the public domain in other countries.
Copies are provided as a preservation service. Particularly outside of the
United States, persons receiving copies should make appropriate efforts to
determine the copyright status of the work in their country and use the
work accordingly. It is possible that current copyright holders, heirs or
the estate of the authors of individual portions of the work, such as
illustrations or photographs, assert copyrights over these portions.
Depending on the nature of subsequent use that is made, additional rights
may need to be obtained independently of anything we can address. The
digital images and OCR of this work were produced by Google, Inc.
(indicated by a watermark on each page in the PageTurner). Google requests
that the images and OCR not be re-hosted, redistributed or used
commercially. The images are provided for educational, scholarly,
non-commercial purposes.
Find this book online: https://hdl. handle. net/2027/mdp. 39015002257767
This file has been created from the computer-extracted text of scanned page
images. Computer-extracted text may have errors, such as misspellings,
unusual characters, odd spacing and line breaks.
Original from: University of Michigan
Digitized by: Google
Generated at University of Chicago on 2023-01-10 06:40 GMT
## p. (#1) ##################################################
B 1,284,344
## p. (#2) ##################################################
University of
Michigan
Libraries
tos SCIENTIA VIITAT
## p. i (#3) ################################################
## p. ii (#4) ###############################################
## p. iii (#5) ##############################################
D
THE
Icile
1923
CAMBRIDGE
MEDIEVAL HISTORY
top 3
PLANNED BY
J. B. BURY, M. A. , F. B. A.
REGIUS PROFESSOR OF MODERN HISTORY
EDITED BY
J. R. TANNER, Litt. D.
C. W. PREVITÉ-ORTON, M. A.
Z. N. BROOKE, M. A.
VOLUME V
CONTEST OF EMPIRE AND PAPACY
NEW YORK
THE MACMILLAN COMPANY
1926
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
IV
502
## p. iv (#6) ###############################################
PRINTED IN GREAT BRITAIN
## p. v (#7) ################################################
GRRY tu to al 2/87
hardoa
au
PREFACE.
N the Preface to Volume IV the Editors referred to the loss which
the enterprise had sustained by the death of Sir Edwin Pears before
he saw his chapter in type, and of M. Ferdinand Chalandon when he
had only seen the first proofs of his chapters, although in this case they
were able to obtain a second revision by Madame Chalandon of her
husband's proofs. They are also indebted to her for a similar revision
in the present volume. But another misfortune has befallen Volume V,
for Count Ugo Balzani died before he could revise his chapters, and this
duty has been discharged by the Editors themselves. They were obliged
to abbreviate them to a certain extent, but except in one instance, duly
indicated in a foot-note, they made no real change in the author's state-
ment of his conclusions.
They wish to express their gratitude to Mrs Stenton for under-
taking the chapter on Henry II of England at short notice, and for the
promptitude with which she completed the work; to Mr C. J. B. Gaskoin
of Jesus College for preparing the maps; and to Mr C. C. Scott, Sub-
Librarian of St John's College, for indispensable assistance in preparing
the bibliographies for the press. The index has been compiled by
Mr E. H. F. Mills of St John's College, the Librarian of the University
of Birmingham.
For the Corrigenda to Volume IV, the Editors are mainly indebted
to the kindness of Mr E. W. Brooks.
Since this Preface was in type, the Cambridge History School has
suffered a grievous loss by the death of Mr W. J. Corbett of King's
College, whose original researches in English history have already lent
distinction to Volumes II and III, and whose last work appears in the
present volume. Even if his researches on Domesday should never now
be published, his main conclusions will be found in the Cambridge
Medieval History.
J. R. T.
C. W. P. -O.
Z. N. B.
January, 1926.
## p. vi (#8) ###############################################
1
## p. vii (#9) ##############################################
INTRODUCTION.
The century and a half, roughly from 1050 to 1200, with which this
volume is concerned, follows on a period when the disorganisation and
anarchy of the ninth century had barely been made good. Order had
been to some extent restored; the desire for order and for peace was at
any rate widespread. The opportunity for fruitful development, both in
the sphere of ecclesiastical and of secular government, and also in those
pursuits which especially needed peace for their prosecution, such as
culture and commerce, had now arrived. We have to deal, then, with a
period, on the one hand, of new movements and new ideas—the appearance
of new monastic orders, a renaissance of thought and learning, the rise of
towns and the expansion of commerce; on the other, of consolidation and
centralisation-the organisation of the monarchical government of the
Church, the development of monarchical institutions in the various
countries of Europe, and, to give direction and solidity to the whole, the
revived study of Civil and Canon Law. Finally, and most novel of all,
we see Europe at once divided by the great conflict of Empire and Papacy
and united by the Crusades in the holy war against the infidel. The
former as well as the latter implies a conception of the unity of Western
Christendom, a unity which found expression in the universal Church,
For the Church alone was universal, European, international; and, as its
institutions begin to take more definite form, the more deeply is this
character impressed upon them.
The volume opens with a chapter on the Reform of the Church,
which was not merely a prelude to, but also a principal cause of, the
striking events that followed; for in the pursuit of the work of reform
the Papacy both developed its own organisation and was brought into
conflict with the secular power. In the first half of the eleventh century,
it had been entirely dominated by the secular interests of the local nobles.
It had been rescued by the Emperor Henry III, and Pope Leo IX had
immediately taken his natural place as leader of the reform movement.
When he undertook personally, in France, Germany, and Italy, the
promulgation and enforcement of the principles of reform, he made the
universality of papal power a reality; the bishops might mutter, but the
people adored. The Papacy was content to take a subordinate place
while Henry III was alive; Henry IV's minority worked a complete
## p. viii (#10) ############################################
viii
Introduction
change. The first great step was the Papal Election Decree of Nicholas
II, and, though the attempt of the Roman nobles to recover their influence
was perhaps the immediate cause, the Papacy took the opportunity to
shake off imperial control as well. An opening for interference still
remained in the case of a disputed election, as was clearly shewn in the
contest of Innocent II and Anastasius II, and especially in that of
Alexander III and Victor IV. This gap was closed by the Third Lateran
Council in 1179, which decreed that whoever obtained the votes of two-
thirds of the cardinals should be declared Pope.
The Papal Election Decree had a further result. By giving to the
cardinals the decision at an election, and reducing other interests to a
merely nominal right of assent, it raised the College of Cardinals to a
position of the highest importance. There were normally at this time
7 (later 6) cardinal-bishops, 28 cardinal-priests, and 18 cardinal-deacons,
and, unless they were employed on papal business, their functions were
confined to Rome. Leo IX had surrounded himself with cardinals who
were reformers like himself; they composed the chief element in the Pope's
Council, or, as it came to be called, the Curia. But he could not find
them in Rome, and had to recruit them from the chief reforming centres,
especially north of the Alps. As they were, and continued to be, drawn from
different countries, so in them was displayed the international character
of the Roman Church; and from their number, in almost every case, was
the Pope elected. A further development came when Alexander III
instituted the practice of including bishops from different parts of
Europe among the cardinals; for the regular duties and residence of such
cardinals were no longer in Rome itself.
The freedom of episcopal elections in general was in the forefront of
the reform programme. The papal policy was to restore canonical
election “by clergy and people," a vague phrase which received its
definition at Rome in the Election Decree. During the twelfth century
a similar definition was arrived at for other sees. The cathedral chapter,
helped by its corporate unity, and especially by the fact that it constituted
the permanent portion of the bishop's concilium and that its consent was
necessary in any disposition of the property of the see, established itself
as the electoral body. To the clergy of the diocese and the lay vassals of
the see was left, as at Rome, only the right of assent and acclamation.
The chapter thus became the local counterpart of the College of Cardinals.
The Papacy was principally concerned with the freedom of elections, and
did not yet claim the right of appointment for itself, except in cases of
dispute. The Third Lateran Council, which gave the decision at a papal
election to a majority vote, expressly decreed that elsewhere the old rule
## p. ix (#11) ##############################################
Introduction
ix
of the “maior et sanior pars” was to hold good; for, with the exception
of Rome, there was a higher authority which could decide in cases of
dispute.
Leo IX had initiated the campaign of reform at Councils in France and
Germany. The Councils over which the Popes presided passed decrees
which were to be universally binding. Usually they were held in Rome,
and regularly in Lent by Gregory VII. In them, besides the Curia, any
leading ecclesiastic who happened to be at the papal court, whether on a
visit or in obedience to a personal summons, took part, just as the nobles
did in a king's Council. A further development occurred in the twelfth
century. Hitherto all the Councils recognised by the Western Church as
Ecumenical had taken place in the East. The schism of 1054 had cut off
the Greek Church from communion with Rome, and in the twelfth
century three Councils were held, each of them at Rome in the Lateran
basilica, which, owing to the importance of their business and the general
rather than particular summonses which were issued, were included later
among the Ecumenical Councils. The First Lateran Council in 1123
ratified the Concordat of Worms, the Second in 1139 solemnised the end
of a schism, and the Third in 1179 the end of another and a greater one.
The next step was the local enforcement of the papal decrees. The
Church had its local officials—archbishops, bishops etc. —and they were
expected both to promulgate the decrees at local synods and to enforce
their execution. It soon became clear that the bishops regarded them-
selves as anything but the docile officials of the central government, and
the Papacy had to establish its authority and to work out a coordinated
system of government by which its policy could be carried into effect.
First of all, for the Pope could no longer do everything in person
like
Leo IX, legates were sent to act in his name, travelling about, like the
Carolingian missi, with overriding authority, to investigate the local
churches and put into force the papal decrees. The appointment of legates
for this general work tends more and more to take a permanent form, and
soon the post of permanent legate—a position of high honour and at the
same time of personal responsibility to the Pope-becomes the prerogative
of the leading ecclesiastics in each country. But the Pope still continued
to send legates from Rome, both as ambassadors to temporal sovereigns
and as functionaries with special commissions; these legates a latere as
direct papal agents again had overriding powers. It was not sufficient,
however, for the Pope to control the local officials through his repre-
sentatives. He insisted on their personal contact with himself. Visits
ad limina were first of all encouraged and then directly ordered, and
archbishops were expected to receive the pallium from the Pope in person. .
## p. x (#12) ###############################################
X
Introduction
It is impossible to say how far at any time this development of papal
authority was deliberate, and how far it arose out of the practical
exigencies of the moment. It became conscious at any rate with Gregory
VII, though even with him the moving cause at first was to enforce the
principles of reform. Opposition, whether from the local officials or from
the lay power, led to a definition of the bases on which this authority
rested and the sphere within which it could be exercised. The decretals,
especially the Forged Decretals, provided a solid foundation, and to
build upon this came opportunely the revived study of the Canon Law.
It is not a question of a finished legal system, but of a continuous process
of construction, in which the legal training of Popes like Urban II and
Alexander III was of great value. Collections of decretals and opinions,
of which Gratian's was the most complete, were continually being added
to by the decrees of Roman Councils and the decisions of Popes given in
their letters. This led to uniformity in ritual also, to the victory of the
Roman use over local customs; for here again it was the Roman that
was to be universal.
In the papal government, even on its ecclesiastical side, there is a
general resemblance to the secular governments of the day. Like a lay
monarch, the Pope was concerned with the organisation of central and
local government, with the formation of a legal system, and with the
recognition of his overriding jurisdiction. When we come to the secular
side of papal government, the resemblance is still more close. Both as
landlord and overlord the Pope acted as any secular ruler, though payments
in money and kind are the usual services rendered to him, rather than
military service; for this he was really dependent on external assistance.
The problem of finance faced him, as it faced every secular ruler. The
work of government, both ecclesiastical and secular, involved the expenses
of government, and, though in ordinary times the revenue from the Papal
States might be sufficient, a period of conflict, by increasing expenditure
or by preventing the Pope from obtaining his ordinary revenues, would
create serious financial difficulties. This was especially the case with
Urban II, and still more with Alexander III, in the crisis of the conflict
with the Empire; and, in the interval of peace, the Pope was seriously
embarrassed by the sustained effort of the Roman people to obtain self-
government.
We have a detailed account of various sources of papal revenue at the
end of our period in the Liber Censuum drawn up under the direction of
the camerarius Cencius, afterwards Pope Honorius III, in the year 1192.
Besides the revenue from the papal domain proper, a census
received: (1) from monasteries who had placed themselves under the papal
was
## p. xi (#13) ##############################################
Introduction
xi
"protection," and who in the course of the twelfth century gained
exemption from the spiritual as well as the temporal control of their
diocesans ; (2) from some lay rulers and nobles, who put themselves under
papal “protection " or, like the kings of Aragon and the Norman rulers
of South Italy and Sicily, recognised papal overlordship; (3) in the form
of Peter's Pence, from England since Anglo-Saxon times, and, in the
twelfth century, from Norway, Sweden, and some other countries as well.
But the census provided only a relatively small revenue, and this was
difficult to collect; there were frequent complaints of arrears of payment,
especially with regard to Peter's Pence. On the other hand, the papal ex-
penditure was often heavy. Alexander III had frequently to have recourse
to borrowing; and his complaints about some of his creditors seem to have
an echo in the decree against usury at the Third Lateran Council. In its
difficulties the Papacy had to depend upon the voluntary offerings of the
faithful, especially from France, on subsidies from the Normans, or on
the support of a wealthy Roman family; thus the Pierleoni constantly
supplied the Popes with money, until one member of the family,
Anacletus II, was defeated in his attempt to ascend the papal throne.
We are still in the early days of papal financial history. Not yet were
the visitation offerings from bishops made compulsory, and the servitia
taxes and annates had not yet been introduced. Nor did the Popes claim
the right to tax the clergy, though perhaps the first step to this was taken
in the second half of the twelfth century, when prohibitions were issued
against the taxation of the clergy by lay rulers without papal consent.
At any rate the desire to finance the Crusades soon led them to assert the
right.
As the Reform Movement had led directly to the creation of a
centralised government of the Church, so too it led, almost inevitably, to
the contest for supremacy between the Papacy and its counterpart on the
secular side, the Empire. Those ecclesiastics whom the Pope expected to
be his obedient officials in the local government of the Church were
already the obedient officials of the Empire both in its central and its
local government. The Pope was on strong ground in insisting that the
spiritual duties of the bishop were his primary consideration. But the
Emperor was on strong ground too. The ecclesiastical nobles were an
essential part of the economic framework and the political machinery of
the Empire, and to justify his authority over them the Emperor could
point to an almost unbroken tradition. The relative importance of
spiritual and temporal considerations in the medieval mind gave an
initial advantage to the Pope, and in the end the victory. On the other
## p. xii (#14) #############################################
xii
Introduction
hand, the Emperor could appeal not only to the iron law of necessity, but
to the medieval reverence for custom and precedent. Henry IV, moreover,
could not forget that the Papacy had itself been subject to his father, and
it was his object to recover what he considered to be his lawful authority.
With this aim he deliberately provoked the contest. The details of the
struggle are described in several chapters in this volume, and need only
be briefly alluded to here. Henry's challenge was taken up by his greater
opponent, Pope Gregory VII, who in his turn claimed the supreme power
for the Papacy; there could be no real peace until the question of
supremacy was settled. Though on this issue the first contest was
indecisive, the Papacy registered a striking advance. The Concordat of
Worms marked a definite limitation of imperial authority over the
ecclesiastical nobility, and it was followed by the reigns of Lothar III and
Conrad III, when the German ruler was too complaisant or too weak to
press his claims. The Pope was emboldened to take the offensive, and
Hadrian IV threw down the challenge that was taken up by Frederick
Barbarossa. The positions were reversed, but again the challenger found
himself faced by a greater opponent, who again defended himself by
asserting his own supremacy. Once more the result was indecisive.
The Pope had a single cause to maintain, the Emperor a dual one.
i Henry IV was defeated by revolt in Germany, Frederick Barbarossa by
revolt in Italy, and both alike had been forced to recognise the
impossibility of maintaining a subservient anti-Pope. But the greatness
of Frederick was never so conspicuous as in his recovery after defeat, and
his son Henry VI seemed to be on the point of making the Empire once
more supreme when death intervened to ruin the imperial cause. Herein
was revealed the second great asset of the Papacy. Built on the rock of
spiritual power, the weakness or death of its head was of little permanent
moment. The Empire, however, depended on the personality of each of
its rulers, and the transference of authority on the deaths of Henry III
and Henry VI was on each occasion disastrous. During the minority of
Henry IV, the Papacy had built up its power; in the minority of
Frederick II, Innocent III was Pope.
In this struggle of Empire and Papacy no insignificant part was played
by the Norman rulers of South Italy and Sicily, whose history falls
exactly within the compass of this volume. Frequently did they come to
the help of the Papacy in its extremity, and skilfully did they make use
of papal exigencies to improve their own position. Only once did the
Pope whom they supported fail to maintain himself; and the victory of
Innocent II over Anastasius II, chosen by a majority of the cardinals and
backed by Norman arms, was in many respects unique. Then, and then
!
REGIUS PROFESSOR OF MODERN HISTORY
EDITED BY
J. R. TANNER, Litt. D.
C. W. PREVITÉ-ORTON, M. A.
Z. N. BROOKE, M. A.
VOLUME V
CONTEST OF EMPIRE AND PAPACY
NEW YORK
THE MACMILLAN COMPANY
1926
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
IV
502
## p. iv (#6) ###############################################
PRINTED IN GREAT BRITAIN
## p. v (#7) ################################################
GRRY tu to al 2/87
hardoa
au
PREFACE.
N the Preface to Volume IV the Editors referred to the loss which
the enterprise had sustained by the death of Sir Edwin Pears before
he saw his chapter in type, and of M. Ferdinand Chalandon when he
had only seen the first proofs of his chapters, although in this case they
were able to obtain a second revision by Madame Chalandon of her
husband's proofs. They are also indebted to her for a similar revision
in the present volume. But another misfortune has befallen Volume V,
for Count Ugo Balzani died before he could revise his chapters, and this
duty has been discharged by the Editors themselves. They were obliged
to abbreviate them to a certain extent, but except in one instance, duly
indicated in a foot-note, they made no real change in the author's state-
ment of his conclusions.
They wish to express their gratitude to Mrs Stenton for under-
taking the chapter on Henry II of England at short notice, and for the
promptitude with which she completed the work; to Mr C. J. B. Gaskoin
of Jesus College for preparing the maps; and to Mr C. C. Scott, Sub-
Librarian of St John's College, for indispensable assistance in preparing
the bibliographies for the press. The index has been compiled by
Mr E. H. F. Mills of St John's College, the Librarian of the University
of Birmingham.
For the Corrigenda to Volume IV, the Editors are mainly indebted
to the kindness of Mr E. W. Brooks.
Since this Preface was in type, the Cambridge History School has
suffered a grievous loss by the death of Mr W. J. Corbett of King's
College, whose original researches in English history have already lent
distinction to Volumes II and III, and whose last work appears in the
present volume. Even if his researches on Domesday should never now
be published, his main conclusions will be found in the Cambridge
Medieval History.
J. R. T.
C. W. P. -O.
Z. N. B.
January, 1926.
## p. vi (#8) ###############################################
1
## p. vii (#9) ##############################################
INTRODUCTION.
The century and a half, roughly from 1050 to 1200, with which this
volume is concerned, follows on a period when the disorganisation and
anarchy of the ninth century had barely been made good. Order had
been to some extent restored; the desire for order and for peace was at
any rate widespread. The opportunity for fruitful development, both in
the sphere of ecclesiastical and of secular government, and also in those
pursuits which especially needed peace for their prosecution, such as
culture and commerce, had now arrived. We have to deal, then, with a
period, on the one hand, of new movements and new ideas—the appearance
of new monastic orders, a renaissance of thought and learning, the rise of
towns and the expansion of commerce; on the other, of consolidation and
centralisation-the organisation of the monarchical government of the
Church, the development of monarchical institutions in the various
countries of Europe, and, to give direction and solidity to the whole, the
revived study of Civil and Canon Law. Finally, and most novel of all,
we see Europe at once divided by the great conflict of Empire and Papacy
and united by the Crusades in the holy war against the infidel. The
former as well as the latter implies a conception of the unity of Western
Christendom, a unity which found expression in the universal Church,
For the Church alone was universal, European, international; and, as its
institutions begin to take more definite form, the more deeply is this
character impressed upon them.
The volume opens with a chapter on the Reform of the Church,
which was not merely a prelude to, but also a principal cause of, the
striking events that followed; for in the pursuit of the work of reform
the Papacy both developed its own organisation and was brought into
conflict with the secular power. In the first half of the eleventh century,
it had been entirely dominated by the secular interests of the local nobles.
It had been rescued by the Emperor Henry III, and Pope Leo IX had
immediately taken his natural place as leader of the reform movement.
When he undertook personally, in France, Germany, and Italy, the
promulgation and enforcement of the principles of reform, he made the
universality of papal power a reality; the bishops might mutter, but the
people adored. The Papacy was content to take a subordinate place
while Henry III was alive; Henry IV's minority worked a complete
## p. viii (#10) ############################################
viii
Introduction
change. The first great step was the Papal Election Decree of Nicholas
II, and, though the attempt of the Roman nobles to recover their influence
was perhaps the immediate cause, the Papacy took the opportunity to
shake off imperial control as well. An opening for interference still
remained in the case of a disputed election, as was clearly shewn in the
contest of Innocent II and Anastasius II, and especially in that of
Alexander III and Victor IV. This gap was closed by the Third Lateran
Council in 1179, which decreed that whoever obtained the votes of two-
thirds of the cardinals should be declared Pope.
The Papal Election Decree had a further result. By giving to the
cardinals the decision at an election, and reducing other interests to a
merely nominal right of assent, it raised the College of Cardinals to a
position of the highest importance. There were normally at this time
7 (later 6) cardinal-bishops, 28 cardinal-priests, and 18 cardinal-deacons,
and, unless they were employed on papal business, their functions were
confined to Rome. Leo IX had surrounded himself with cardinals who
were reformers like himself; they composed the chief element in the Pope's
Council, or, as it came to be called, the Curia. But he could not find
them in Rome, and had to recruit them from the chief reforming centres,
especially north of the Alps. As they were, and continued to be, drawn from
different countries, so in them was displayed the international character
of the Roman Church; and from their number, in almost every case, was
the Pope elected. A further development came when Alexander III
instituted the practice of including bishops from different parts of
Europe among the cardinals; for the regular duties and residence of such
cardinals were no longer in Rome itself.
The freedom of episcopal elections in general was in the forefront of
the reform programme. The papal policy was to restore canonical
election “by clergy and people," a vague phrase which received its
definition at Rome in the Election Decree. During the twelfth century
a similar definition was arrived at for other sees. The cathedral chapter,
helped by its corporate unity, and especially by the fact that it constituted
the permanent portion of the bishop's concilium and that its consent was
necessary in any disposition of the property of the see, established itself
as the electoral body. To the clergy of the diocese and the lay vassals of
the see was left, as at Rome, only the right of assent and acclamation.
The chapter thus became the local counterpart of the College of Cardinals.
The Papacy was principally concerned with the freedom of elections, and
did not yet claim the right of appointment for itself, except in cases of
dispute. The Third Lateran Council, which gave the decision at a papal
election to a majority vote, expressly decreed that elsewhere the old rule
## p. ix (#11) ##############################################
Introduction
ix
of the “maior et sanior pars” was to hold good; for, with the exception
of Rome, there was a higher authority which could decide in cases of
dispute.
Leo IX had initiated the campaign of reform at Councils in France and
Germany. The Councils over which the Popes presided passed decrees
which were to be universally binding. Usually they were held in Rome,
and regularly in Lent by Gregory VII. In them, besides the Curia, any
leading ecclesiastic who happened to be at the papal court, whether on a
visit or in obedience to a personal summons, took part, just as the nobles
did in a king's Council. A further development occurred in the twelfth
century. Hitherto all the Councils recognised by the Western Church as
Ecumenical had taken place in the East. The schism of 1054 had cut off
the Greek Church from communion with Rome, and in the twelfth
century three Councils were held, each of them at Rome in the Lateran
basilica, which, owing to the importance of their business and the general
rather than particular summonses which were issued, were included later
among the Ecumenical Councils. The First Lateran Council in 1123
ratified the Concordat of Worms, the Second in 1139 solemnised the end
of a schism, and the Third in 1179 the end of another and a greater one.
The next step was the local enforcement of the papal decrees. The
Church had its local officials—archbishops, bishops etc. —and they were
expected both to promulgate the decrees at local synods and to enforce
their execution. It soon became clear that the bishops regarded them-
selves as anything but the docile officials of the central government, and
the Papacy had to establish its authority and to work out a coordinated
system of government by which its policy could be carried into effect.
First of all, for the Pope could no longer do everything in person
like
Leo IX, legates were sent to act in his name, travelling about, like the
Carolingian missi, with overriding authority, to investigate the local
churches and put into force the papal decrees. The appointment of legates
for this general work tends more and more to take a permanent form, and
soon the post of permanent legate—a position of high honour and at the
same time of personal responsibility to the Pope-becomes the prerogative
of the leading ecclesiastics in each country. But the Pope still continued
to send legates from Rome, both as ambassadors to temporal sovereigns
and as functionaries with special commissions; these legates a latere as
direct papal agents again had overriding powers. It was not sufficient,
however, for the Pope to control the local officials through his repre-
sentatives. He insisted on their personal contact with himself. Visits
ad limina were first of all encouraged and then directly ordered, and
archbishops were expected to receive the pallium from the Pope in person. .
## p. x (#12) ###############################################
X
Introduction
It is impossible to say how far at any time this development of papal
authority was deliberate, and how far it arose out of the practical
exigencies of the moment. It became conscious at any rate with Gregory
VII, though even with him the moving cause at first was to enforce the
principles of reform. Opposition, whether from the local officials or from
the lay power, led to a definition of the bases on which this authority
rested and the sphere within which it could be exercised. The decretals,
especially the Forged Decretals, provided a solid foundation, and to
build upon this came opportunely the revived study of the Canon Law.
It is not a question of a finished legal system, but of a continuous process
of construction, in which the legal training of Popes like Urban II and
Alexander III was of great value. Collections of decretals and opinions,
of which Gratian's was the most complete, were continually being added
to by the decrees of Roman Councils and the decisions of Popes given in
their letters. This led to uniformity in ritual also, to the victory of the
Roman use over local customs; for here again it was the Roman that
was to be universal.
In the papal government, even on its ecclesiastical side, there is a
general resemblance to the secular governments of the day. Like a lay
monarch, the Pope was concerned with the organisation of central and
local government, with the formation of a legal system, and with the
recognition of his overriding jurisdiction. When we come to the secular
side of papal government, the resemblance is still more close. Both as
landlord and overlord the Pope acted as any secular ruler, though payments
in money and kind are the usual services rendered to him, rather than
military service; for this he was really dependent on external assistance.
The problem of finance faced him, as it faced every secular ruler. The
work of government, both ecclesiastical and secular, involved the expenses
of government, and, though in ordinary times the revenue from the Papal
States might be sufficient, a period of conflict, by increasing expenditure
or by preventing the Pope from obtaining his ordinary revenues, would
create serious financial difficulties. This was especially the case with
Urban II, and still more with Alexander III, in the crisis of the conflict
with the Empire; and, in the interval of peace, the Pope was seriously
embarrassed by the sustained effort of the Roman people to obtain self-
government.
We have a detailed account of various sources of papal revenue at the
end of our period in the Liber Censuum drawn up under the direction of
the camerarius Cencius, afterwards Pope Honorius III, in the year 1192.
Besides the revenue from the papal domain proper, a census
received: (1) from monasteries who had placed themselves under the papal
was
## p. xi (#13) ##############################################
Introduction
xi
"protection," and who in the course of the twelfth century gained
exemption from the spiritual as well as the temporal control of their
diocesans ; (2) from some lay rulers and nobles, who put themselves under
papal “protection " or, like the kings of Aragon and the Norman rulers
of South Italy and Sicily, recognised papal overlordship; (3) in the form
of Peter's Pence, from England since Anglo-Saxon times, and, in the
twelfth century, from Norway, Sweden, and some other countries as well.
But the census provided only a relatively small revenue, and this was
difficult to collect; there were frequent complaints of arrears of payment,
especially with regard to Peter's Pence. On the other hand, the papal ex-
penditure was often heavy. Alexander III had frequently to have recourse
to borrowing; and his complaints about some of his creditors seem to have
an echo in the decree against usury at the Third Lateran Council. In its
difficulties the Papacy had to depend upon the voluntary offerings of the
faithful, especially from France, on subsidies from the Normans, or on
the support of a wealthy Roman family; thus the Pierleoni constantly
supplied the Popes with money, until one member of the family,
Anacletus II, was defeated in his attempt to ascend the papal throne.
We are still in the early days of papal financial history. Not yet were
the visitation offerings from bishops made compulsory, and the servitia
taxes and annates had not yet been introduced. Nor did the Popes claim
the right to tax the clergy, though perhaps the first step to this was taken
in the second half of the twelfth century, when prohibitions were issued
against the taxation of the clergy by lay rulers without papal consent.
At any rate the desire to finance the Crusades soon led them to assert the
right.
As the Reform Movement had led directly to the creation of a
centralised government of the Church, so too it led, almost inevitably, to
the contest for supremacy between the Papacy and its counterpart on the
secular side, the Empire. Those ecclesiastics whom the Pope expected to
be his obedient officials in the local government of the Church were
already the obedient officials of the Empire both in its central and its
local government. The Pope was on strong ground in insisting that the
spiritual duties of the bishop were his primary consideration. But the
Emperor was on strong ground too. The ecclesiastical nobles were an
essential part of the economic framework and the political machinery of
the Empire, and to justify his authority over them the Emperor could
point to an almost unbroken tradition. The relative importance of
spiritual and temporal considerations in the medieval mind gave an
initial advantage to the Pope, and in the end the victory. On the other
## p. xii (#14) #############################################
xii
Introduction
hand, the Emperor could appeal not only to the iron law of necessity, but
to the medieval reverence for custom and precedent. Henry IV, moreover,
could not forget that the Papacy had itself been subject to his father, and
it was his object to recover what he considered to be his lawful authority.
With this aim he deliberately provoked the contest. The details of the
struggle are described in several chapters in this volume, and need only
be briefly alluded to here. Henry's challenge was taken up by his greater
opponent, Pope Gregory VII, who in his turn claimed the supreme power
for the Papacy; there could be no real peace until the question of
supremacy was settled. Though on this issue the first contest was
indecisive, the Papacy registered a striking advance. The Concordat of
Worms marked a definite limitation of imperial authority over the
ecclesiastical nobility, and it was followed by the reigns of Lothar III and
Conrad III, when the German ruler was too complaisant or too weak to
press his claims. The Pope was emboldened to take the offensive, and
Hadrian IV threw down the challenge that was taken up by Frederick
Barbarossa. The positions were reversed, but again the challenger found
himself faced by a greater opponent, who again defended himself by
asserting his own supremacy. Once more the result was indecisive.
The Pope had a single cause to maintain, the Emperor a dual one.
i Henry IV was defeated by revolt in Germany, Frederick Barbarossa by
revolt in Italy, and both alike had been forced to recognise the
impossibility of maintaining a subservient anti-Pope. But the greatness
of Frederick was never so conspicuous as in his recovery after defeat, and
his son Henry VI seemed to be on the point of making the Empire once
more supreme when death intervened to ruin the imperial cause. Herein
was revealed the second great asset of the Papacy. Built on the rock of
spiritual power, the weakness or death of its head was of little permanent
moment. The Empire, however, depended on the personality of each of
its rulers, and the transference of authority on the deaths of Henry III
and Henry VI was on each occasion disastrous. During the minority of
Henry IV, the Papacy had built up its power; in the minority of
Frederick II, Innocent III was Pope.
In this struggle of Empire and Papacy no insignificant part was played
by the Norman rulers of South Italy and Sicily, whose history falls
exactly within the compass of this volume. Frequently did they come to
the help of the Papacy in its extremity, and skilfully did they make use
of papal exigencies to improve their own position. Only once did the
Pope whom they supported fail to maintain himself; and the victory of
Innocent II over Anastasius II, chosen by a majority of the cardinals and
backed by Norman arms, was in many respects unique. Then, and then
!
## p. xiii (#15) ############################################
Introduction
xiii
only, did Pope and Emperor combine against the Normans, but there was
no stability in an alliance so unusual. In the Sicilian kingdom were
displayed the peculiar characteristics of the Norman race—its military
prowess and ferocity, its genius for administration, its adaptability and
eclecticism. They brought from Normandy the feudal customs they had
there acquired, but they maintained and converted to their use the
officials and institutions, the arts and sciences, of the races they conquered-
Italian, Greek, and Arab—each of which was tolerated in the use of its
own language, religion, and customs. The court of Roger II at Palermo
presented an appearance unlike anything else in the West; and the
essential product of this extraordinary environment was “the wonder of
the world,” Frederick II. The Normans pieced together a most remarkable
mosaic, but they never made a nation of their subjects; the elements were
too discordant, and they themselves too few. They remained a ruling
caste, and then, as the royal house, once so prolific, gradually became
sterile, Frederick Barbarossa seized the opportunity to marry his son
Henry VI to the heiress Constance and to unite the crowns of Germany
and Sicily. But, though the Norman rulers had disappeared, their deeds
survived; for their own purposes they had recognised papal overlordship
and received from the Pope their titles as dukes and kings. By so doing
they added materially to the temporal authority of the Papacy, and
created the situation which made so bitter the conflict of Empire and
Papacy in the thirteenth century.
As the Normans exercised an important influence on the great
struggle which divided the unity of Europe, so did they also have a de-
cisive effect upon the other great struggle, in which Europe was united
against the infidel. The story of the Crusades is described in this volume
from the Western point of view, and it has already been told from the
Eastern standpoint in Volume IV. Its importance in world-history, and
also in the more limited field of European history, need not be stressed
here; but it is worth while to characterise the different interests involved,
and to regard the Crusading movement in its proper setting, as an episode
in the general history of the relations of East and West. It was not
merely a Holy War between Christian and Muslim. The Seljūqs, already
in decline and hampered by internal divisions, were concerned with the
effort to maintain what they had won. The Eastern Empire was con-
cerned firstly with the defence of its existence, secondly with the recovery
of Asia Minor. The Latins, to whom they appealed for help, were inte-
rested rather in Syria and Palestine, to which they were equally attracted
by religious enthusiasm and by the prospects of territory or trade. Europe
also had its own injuries to avenge. It too had suffered from Saracen
C. MED. H. VOL. V.
b
## p. xiv (#16) #############################################
xiv
Introduction
invaders, against whom it was now beginning to react—in the advance of
the Christian kingdoms in Spain, in the Norman conquest of Sicily, in
the capture of Mahdiyah by Genoa and Pisa in 1087. The Crusades were,
in one aspect, an extension Eastwards of this reaction, a change
from the defensive to the offensive. Against a common foe Eastern and
Western Christians had a common cause, but the concord went no further.
In the first place, seventeen years before the fatal battle of Manzikert,
which had caused the Eastern Empire to turn to the West for aid, the
great Schism between the Eastern and Western Churches had already
occurred. One of the results hoped for from the First Crusade was the
healing of that schism, and to the Western mind the obstinate perversity
of the Greek Church made it as dangerous an enemy of the faith as
Mohammedanism itself. And, secondly, the Normans in South Italy had
conquered Greeks as well as Saracens, and their first advance eastwards
was against Greeks not against Saracens. Robert Guiscard by his attack
on the Eastern Empire in 1081 began the policy, which was continued
by his successors and was adopted by the Emperor Henry VI as part of
his Norman inheritance. In other quarters, too, the experiences of the
first two Crusades created a body of opinion in favour of the conquest of
the Eastern Empire as a necessary part of the whole movement; this
opinion gathered strength when the Eastern Emperor came to terms with
Saladin to oppose the Western advance which was now a menace to both.
Finally, Venice was alienated by the ambition of Manuel Comnenus and
the folly of Andronicus, and from being the chief obstacle to the Norman
policy became its chief supporter. It was now the aim of the Crusaders
to conquer the whole of the Near East, Christian and Muslim alike, and
their first objective was Constantinople.
In the internal history of Europe this volume deals, outside Italy,
with the three leading countries of Germany, France, and England; the
history of the outlying and more backward countries—Spain, Scandinavia,
Poland, Bohemia, Hungary-is reserved for the next volume. In these
three countries there was much that was similar, for the underlying ideas
inherent in feudal society were common to them all. But similar concep-
tions produced widely differing results. On the one hand, feudal society
with its deep reverence for custom and tradition was much affected by
local conditions and lapse of time. On the other hand, it was peculiarly
sensitive to the workings of human nature, to the ambition of individuals
who stressed the privileges and minimised the obligations arising from the
idea of contract on which the feudal system was essentially based; it was
poised on a delicate balance which the accident of death might immedi-
## p. xv (#17) ##############################################
1
Introduction
XV
ately upset. In the secular governments, as in the ecclesiastical government
of the Church, the trend is in favour of monarchy, and the rulers make,
with varying success, a continual effort towards centralisation; but they
were all at an initial disadvantage compared with the Pope. The success
of the electoral principle might be fatal to monarchical authority; and
the hereditary principle had its dangers too, in the event of a minority
or the failure of a direct heir. The hereditary principle could not be
applied to the Papacy, for which the electoral system worked as a means
of continual development; for the cardinals, having no opportunity of
obtaining an independent position apart from the Pope, had everything
to gain as individuals and nothing to lose by electing the ablest of their
number as Pope.
Monarchy was in the most favourable position in England, and here
it was therefore the most successful. William I started with the initial
advantage that the whole land was his by conquest, and to be dealt with as
he chose. The Normans, here as in Sicily, displayed their genius in adminis-
tration, their adaptability and eclecticism. The political feudalism they
brought from Normandy placed the king in England in the strong posi-
tion that, as duke, he had held in Normandy; and he adopted what he
found suitable to his purpose already existing—the manorial system, the
shire and hundred courts, Danegeld.
